Preface |
|
xvii | |
|
|
1 | (24) |
|
|
2 | (1) |
|
Labor Economics: Some Basic Concepts |
|
|
2 | (10) |
|
|
3 | (1) |
|
The Models and Predictions of Positive Economics |
|
|
4 | (3) |
|
|
7 | (3) |
|
Normative Economics and Government Policy |
|
|
10 | (2) |
|
|
12 | (13) |
|
Example 1.1 Positive Economics: What Does It Mean to ``Understand'' Behavior? |
|
|
5 | (11) |
|
Appendix 1A Statistical Testing of Labor Market Hypotheses |
|
|
16 | (9) |
|
Overview of the Labor Market |
|
|
25 | (34) |
|
The Labor Market: Definitions, Facts, and Trends |
|
|
26 | (9) |
|
The Labor Force and Unemployment |
|
|
27 | (3) |
|
Industries and Occupations: Adapting to Change |
|
|
30 | (1) |
|
|
30 | (5) |
|
How the Labor Market Works |
|
|
35 | (12) |
|
|
36 | (4) |
|
|
40 | (2) |
|
The Determination of the Wage |
|
|
42 | (5) |
|
Applications of the Theory |
|
|
47 | (12) |
|
Who Is Underpaid and Who Is Overpaid? |
|
|
47 | (6) |
|
International Differences in Unemployment |
|
|
53 | |
|
Example 2.1 The Black Death and the Wages of Labor |
|
|
45 | (5) |
|
Example 2.2 Ending the Conscription of Young American Men: The Role of Economists |
|
|
50 | (2) |
|
Empirical Study Pay Levels and the Supply of Military Officers: Obtaining Sample Variation from Cross-Section Data |
|
|
52 | (7) |
|
|
59 | (34) |
|
|
60 | (3) |
|
Marginal Income from an Additional Unit of Input |
|
|
61 | (2) |
|
Marginal Expense of an Added Input |
|
|
63 | (1) |
|
The Short-Run Demand for Labor When Both Product and Labor Markets Are Competitive |
|
|
63 | (7) |
|
A Critical Assumption: Declining MPL |
|
|
64 | (1) |
|
From Profit Maximization to Labor Demand |
|
|
65 | (5) |
|
The Demand for Labor in Competitive Markets When Other Inputs Can Be Varied |
|
|
70 | (4) |
|
Labor Demand in the Long Run |
|
|
70 | (2) |
|
|
72 | (2) |
|
Labor Demand When the Product Market Is Not Competitive |
|
|
74 | (2) |
|
Maximizing Monopoly Profits |
|
|
74 | (1) |
|
Do Monopolies Pay Higher Wages? |
|
|
75 | (1) |
|
Policy Application: The Labor Market Effects of Employer Payroll Taxes and Wage Subsidies |
|
|
76 | (17) |
|
Who Bears the Burden of a Payroll Tax? |
|
|
76 | (3) |
|
Employment Subsidies as a Device to Help the Poor |
|
|
79 | |
|
Example 3.1 The Marginal Revenue Product of College Football Stars |
|
|
62 | (10) |
|
Example 3.2 Coal Mining Wages and Capital Substitution |
|
|
72 | (8) |
|
Empirical Study Do Women Pay for Employer-Funded Maternity Benefits? Using Cross-Section Data over Time to Analyze ``Differences in Differences'' |
|
|
80 | (5) |
|
Appendix 3A Graphical Derivation of a Firm's Labor Demand Curve |
|
|
85 | (8) |
|
Labor Demand Elasticities |
|
|
93 | (36) |
|
The Own-Wage Elasticity of Demand |
|
|
94 | (9) |
|
The Hicks-Marshall Laws of Derived Demand |
|
|
96 | (3) |
|
Estimates of Own-Wage Labor Demand Elasticities |
|
|
99 | (2) |
|
Applying the Laws of Derived Demand: Inferential Analysis |
|
|
101 | (2) |
|
The Cross-Wage Elasticity of Demand |
|
|
103 | (4) |
|
Can the Laws of Derived Demand Be Applied to Cross-Elasticities? |
|
|
104 | (2) |
|
Estimates Relating to Cross-Elasticities |
|
|
106 | (1) |
|
Policy Application: Effects of Minimum Wage Laws |
|
|
107 | (8) |
|
|
107 | (1) |
|
Employment Effects: Theoretical Analysis |
|
|
108 | (4) |
|
Employment Effects: Empirical Estimates |
|
|
112 | (2) |
|
Does the Minimum Wage Fight Poverty? |
|
|
114 | (1) |
|
Applying Concepts of Labor Demand Elasticity to the Issue of Technological Change |
|
|
115 | (14) |
|
Example 4.1 Why Are Union Wages So Different in Two Parts of the Trucking Industry? |
|
|
102 | (11) |
|
Example 4.2 The Employment Effects of the First Federal Minimum Wage |
|
|
113 | (3) |
|
Empirical Study Estimating the Labor Demand Curve: Time Series Data and Coping with ``Simultaneity'' |
|
|
116 | (6) |
|
Appendix 4A International Trade and the Demand for Labor: Can High-Wage Countries Compete? |
|
|
122 | (7) |
|
Frictions in the Labor Market |
|
|
129 | (36) |
|
Frictions on the Employee Side of the Market |
|
|
130 | (15) |
|
|
130 | (3) |
|
Monopsonistic Labor Markets: A Definition |
|
|
133 | (1) |
|
Profit Maximization under Monopsonistic Conditions |
|
|
134 | (4) |
|
How Do Monopsonistic Firms Respond to Shifts in the Supply Curve? |
|
|
138 | (2) |
|
Monopsonistic Conditions and the Employment Response to Minimum Wage Legislation |
|
|
140 | (2) |
|
Job Search Costs and Other Labor Market Outcomes |
|
|
142 | (2) |
|
Monopsonistic Conditions and the Relevance of the Competitive Model |
|
|
144 | (1) |
|
Frictions on the Employer Side of the Market |
|
|
145 | (8) |
|
Categories of Quasi-Fixed Costs |
|
|
145 | (4) |
|
The Employment/Hours Trade-Off |
|
|
149 | (4) |
|
|
153 | (4) |
|
The Training Decision by Employers |
|
|
153 | (1) |
|
|
153 | (1) |
|
Training and Post-Training Wage Increases |
|
|
154 | (2) |
|
Employer Training Investments and Recessionary Layoffs |
|
|
156 | (1) |
|
|
157 | (8) |
|
|
158 | (1) |
|
|
159 | (2) |
|
How Can the Employer Recoup Its Hiring Investments? |
|
|
161 | |
|
Example 5.1 Does Employment Protection Legislation Protect Workers? |
|
|
146 | (4) |
|
Example 5.2 ``Renting'' Workers as a Way of Coping with Hiring Costs |
|
|
150 | (8) |
|
Example 5.3 Why Do Temporary-Help Firms Provide Free General Skills Training? |
|
|
158 | (2) |
|
Empirical Study What Explains Wage Differences for Workers Who Appear Similar? Using Panel Data to Deal with Unobserved Heterogeneity |
|
|
160 | (5) |
|
Supply of Labor to the Economy: the Decision to Work |
|
|
165 | (42) |
|
Trends in Labor Force Participation and Hours of Work |
|
|
166 | (9) |
|
Labor Force Participation Rates |
|
|
166 | (2) |
|
|
168 | (7) |
|
A Theory of the Decision to Work |
|
|
175 | (17) |
|
|
170 | (5) |
|
Analysis of the Labor/Leisure Choice |
|
|
175 | (14) |
|
Empirical Findings on the Income and Substitution Effects |
|
|
189 | (3) |
|
|
192 | (15) |
|
Budget Constraints with ``Spikes'' |
|
|
192 | (3) |
|
Programs with Net Wage Rates of Zero |
|
|
195 | (5) |
|
Subsidy Programs with Positive Net Wage Rates |
|
|
200 | |
|
Example 6.1 The Labor Supply of Pigeons |
|
|
173 | (13) |
|
Example 6.2 Do Large Inheritances Induce Labor Force Withdrawal? |
|
|
186 | (2) |
|
Example 6.3 Daily Labor Supply at the Ballpark |
|
|
188 | (3) |
|
Example 6.4 Labor Supply Effects of Income Tax Cuts |
|
|
191 | (4) |
|
Example 6.5 Staying Around One's Kentucky Home: Workers' Compensation Benefits and the Return to Work |
|
|
195 | (4) |
|
Example 6.6 Wartime Food Requisitions and Agricultural Work Incentives |
|
|
199 | (3) |
|
Empirical Study Estimating the Income Effect Among Lottery Winners: The Search for ``Exogeneity'' |
|
|
202 | (5) |
|
Labor Supply: Household Production, the Family, and the Life Cycle |
|
|
207 | (32) |
|
The Theory of Household Production |
|
|
208 | (3) |
|
|
208 | (2) |
|
Implications of the Model |
|
|
210 | (1) |
|
The Tripartite Choice: Market Work, Household Work, and Leisure |
|
|
211 | (4) |
|
Time Use by Women and Men |
|
|
211 | (2) |
|
|
213 | (2) |
|
Joint Labor Supply Decisions within the Household |
|
|
215 | (6) |
|
Specialization of Function |
|
|
215 | (1) |
|
Do Both Partners Work for Pay? |
|
|
216 | (1) |
|
The Joint Decision and Cross-Effects |
|
|
217 | (2) |
|
Labor Supply in Recessions: The ``Discouraged'' versus the ``Added'' Worker |
|
|
219 | (2) |
|
Life-Cycle Aspects of Labor Supply |
|
|
221 | (8) |
|
The Labor Force Participation Patterns of Married Women |
|
|
221 | (2) |
|
The Substitution Effect and When to Work over a Lifetime |
|
|
223 | (2) |
|
The Choice of Retirement Age |
|
|
225 | (4) |
|
Policy Application: Child Care and Labor Supply |
|
|
229 | (10) |
|
|
229 | (2) |
|
|
231 | |
|
Example 7.1 Obesity and the Household Production Model |
|
|
212 | (6) |
|
Example 7.2 Husbands, Wives, Neighbors, and the End of the Six-Hour Workday at Kellogg's |
|
|
218 | (5) |
|
Example 7.3 The Value of a Homemaker's Time |
|
|
223 | (11) |
|
Empirical Study The Effects of Wage Increases on Labor Supply (and Sleep): Time-Use Diary Data and Sample Selection Bias |
|
|
234 | (5) |
|
Compensating Wage Differentials and Labor Markets |
|
|
239 | (36) |
|
Job Matching: The Role of Worker Preferences and Information |
|
|
239 | (7) |
|
Individual Choice and Its Outcomes |
|
|
240 | (2) |
|
Assumptions and Predictions |
|
|
242 | (2) |
|
Empirical Tests for Compensating Wage Differentials |
|
|
244 | (2) |
|
Hedonic Wage Theory and the Risk of Injury |
|
|
246 | (14) |
|
|
247 | (1) |
|
|
248 | (2) |
|
The Matching of Employers and Employees |
|
|
250 | (4) |
|
Normative Analysis: Occupational Safety and Health Regulation |
|
|
254 | (6) |
|
Hedonic Wage Theory and Employee Benefits |
|
|
260 | (15) |
|
|
260 | (1) |
|
|
261 | (4) |
|
The Joint Determination of Wages and Benefits |
|
|
265 | |
|
Example 8.1 Working on the Railroad: Making a Bad Job Good |
|
|
246 | (7) |
|
Example 8.2 Parenthood, Occupational Choice, and Risk |
|
|
253 | (2) |
|
Example 8.3 Compensating Wage Differentials in Nineteenth-Century Britain |
|
|
255 | (9) |
|
Empirical Study How Risky Are Estimates of Compensating Wage Differentials for Risk? The ``Errors in Variables'' Problem |
|
|
264 | (6) |
|
Appendix 8A Compensating Wage Differentials and Layoffs |
|
|
270 | (5) |
|
Investments in Human Capital: Education and Training |
|
|
275 | (48) |
|
Human Capital Investments: The Basic Model |
|
|
277 | (4) |
|
The Concept of Present Value |
|
|
277 | (2) |
|
Modeling the Human Capital Investment Decision |
|
|
279 | (2) |
|
The Demand for a College Education |
|
|
281 | (7) |
|
Weighing the Costs and Benefits of College |
|
|
281 | (1) |
|
Predictions of the Theory |
|
|
282 | (5) |
|
Market Responses to Changes in College Attendance |
|
|
287 | (1) |
|
Education, Earnings, and Post-schooling Investments in Human Capital |
|
|
288 | (9) |
|
Average Earnings and Educational Level |
|
|
288 | (2) |
|
On-the-Job Training and the Concavity of Age/Earnings Profiles |
|
|
290 | (2) |
|
The Fanning Out of Age/Earnings Profiles |
|
|
292 | (1) |
|
Women and the Acquisition of Human Capital |
|
|
293 | (4) |
|
Is Education a Good Investment? |
|
|
297 | (26) |
|
Is Education a Good Investment for Individuals? |
|
|
297 | (3) |
|
Is Education a Good Social Investment? |
|
|
300 | (8) |
|
Is Public Sector Training a Good Social Investment? |
|
|
308 | |
|
Example 9.1 War and Human Capital |
|
|
276 | (9) |
|
Example 9.2 Did the G.I. Bill Increase Educational Attainment for Returning World War II Vets? |
|
|
285 | (13) |
|
Example 9.3 Valuing a Human Asset: The Case of the Divorcing Doctor |
|
|
298 | (8) |
|
Example 9.4 The Socially Optimal Level of Educational Investment |
|
|
306 | (4) |
|
Empirical Study Estimating the Returns to Education Using a Sample of Twins: Coping with the Problem of Unobserved Differences in Ability |
|
|
310 | (3) |
|
Appendix 9A A ``Cobweb'' Model of Labor Market Adjustment |
|
|
313 | (4) |
|
Appendix 9B A Hedonic Model of Earnings and Educational Level |
|
|
317 | (6) |
|
Worker Mobility: Migration, Immigration, and Turnover |
|
|
323 | (30) |
|
The Determinants of Worker Mobility |
|
|
324 | (1) |
|
|
325 | (8) |
|
The Direction of Migratory Flows |
|
|
326 | (1) |
|
Personal Characteristics of Movers |
|
|
326 | (2) |
|
|
328 | (1) |
|
The Earnings Distribution in Sending Countries and International Migration |
|
|
329 | (1) |
|
The Returns to International and Domestic Migration |
|
|
330 | (3) |
|
Policy Application: Restricting Immigration |
|
|
333 | (10) |
|
|
333 | (3) |
|
Naive Views of Immigration |
|
|
336 | (2) |
|
An Analysis of the Gainers and Losers |
|
|
338 | (2) |
|
Do the Overall Gains from Immigration Exceed the Losses? |
|
|
340 | (3) |
|
|
343 | (10) |
|
|
344 | (1) |
|
|
344 | (1) |
|
|
345 | (1) |
|
|
345 | (1) |
|
|
346 | (1) |
|
International Comparisons |
|
|
346 | (3) |
|
|
349 | |
|
Example 10.1 The Great Migration: Southern Blacks Move North |
|
|
327 | (2) |
|
Example 10.2 Migration and One's Time Horizon |
|
|
329 | (12) |
|
Example 10.3 The Mariel Boatlift and Its Effects on Miami's Wage and Unemployment Rates |
|
|
341 | (7) |
|
Empirical Study Do Political Refugees Invest More in Human Capital than Economic Immigrants? The Use of Synthetic Cohorts |
|
|
348 | (5) |
|
Pay and Productivity: Wage Determination Within the Firm |
|
|
353 | (36) |
|
Motivating Workers: An Overview of the Fundamentals |
|
|
355 | (7) |
|
|
355 | (1) |
|
Coping with Information Asymmetries |
|
|
356 | (2) |
|
|
358 | (2) |
|
Motivating the Individual in a Group |
|
|
360 | (2) |
|
Compensation Plans: Overview and Guide to the Rest of the Chapter |
|
|
362 | (1) |
|
Productivity and the Basis of Yearly Pay |
|
|
362 | (7) |
|
|
362 | (1) |
|
|
363 | (6) |
|
Productivity and the Level of Pay |
|
|
369 | (3) |
|
Why Higher Pay Might Increase Worker Productivity |
|
|
369 | (1) |
|
|
370 | (2) |
|
Productivity and the Sequencing of Pay |
|
|
372 | (8) |
|
Underpayment Followed by Overpayment |
|
|
373 | (3) |
|
|
376 | (2) |
|
Career Concerns and Productivity |
|
|
378 | (2) |
|
Applications of the Theory: Explaining Two Puzzles |
|
|
380 | (9) |
|
Why Do Earnings Increase with Job Tenure? |
|
|
380 | (2) |
|
Why Do Large Firms Pay More? |
|
|
382 | |
|
Example 11.1 The Wide Range of Possible Productivities: The Case of the Factory That Could Not Cut Output |
|
|
354 | (6) |
|
Example 11.2 Calorie Consumption and the Type of Pay |
|
|
360 | (6) |
|
Example 11.3 Poor Group Incentives Doom the Shakers |
|
|
366 | (5) |
|
Example 11.4 Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? |
|
|
371 | (7) |
|
Example 11.5 Demanding Employers, Overworked Employees, and Neglected Families |
|
|
378 | (6) |
|
Empirical Study Are Workers Willing to Pay for Fairness? Using Laboratory Experiments to Study Economic Behavior |
|
|
384 | (5) |
|
Gender, Race, and Ethnicity in the Labor Market |
|
|
389 | (48) |
|
Measured and Unmeasured Sources of Earnings Differences |
|
|
391 | (15) |
|
Earnings Differences by Gender |
|
|
391 | (9) |
|
Earnings Differences between Black and White Americans |
|
|
400 | (4) |
|
Earnings Differences by Ethnicity |
|
|
404 | (2) |
|
Theories of Market Discrimination |
|
|
406 | (14) |
|
Personal Prejudice Models: Employer Discrimination |
|
|
407 | (4) |
|
Personal Prejudice Models: Customer Discrimination |
|
|
411 | (1) |
|
Personal Prejudice Models: Employee Discrimination |
|
|
412 | (2) |
|
Statistical Discrimination |
|
|
414 | (1) |
|
Noncompetitive Models of Discrimination |
|
|
415 | (4) |
|
A Final Word on the Theories of Discrimination |
|
|
419 | (1) |
|
Federal Programs to End Discrimination |
|
|
420 | (17) |
|
|
420 | (1) |
|
Title VII of the Civil Rights Act |
|
|
420 | (3) |
|
The Federal Contract Compliance Program |
|
|
423 | (3) |
|
Effectiveness of Federal Antidiscrimination Programs |
|
|
426 | |
|
Example 12.1 Bias in the Selection of Musicians by Symphony Orchestras |
|
|
394 | (3) |
|
Example 12.2 The Gender Earnings Gap across Countries |
|
|
397 | (16) |
|
Example 12.3 Fear and Lathing in the Michigan Furniture Industry |
|
|
413 | (11) |
|
Example 12.4 Comparable Worth and the University |
|
|
424 | (4) |
|
Empirical Study Can We Catch Discriminators in the Act? The Use of Field Experiments in Identifying Labor Market Discrimination |
|
|
428 | (5) |
|
Appendix 12A Estimating Comparable-Worth Earnings Gaps: An Application of Regression Analysis |
|
|
433 | (4) |
|
Unions and the Labor Market |
|
|
437 | (50) |
|
Union Structure and Membership |
|
|
438 | (5) |
|
International Comparisons of Unionism |
|
|
438 | (2) |
|
The Legal Structure of Unions in the United States |
|
|
440 | (3) |
|
Constraints on the Achievement of Union Objectives |
|
|
443 | (7) |
|
|
445 | (1) |
|
The Efficient-Contracts Model |
|
|
446 | (4) |
|
The Activities and Tools of Collective Bargaining |
|
|
450 | (16) |
|
Union Membership: An Analysis of Demand and Supply |
|
|
451 | (5) |
|
Union Actions to Alter the Labor Demand Curve |
|
|
456 | (2) |
|
Bargaining and the Threat of Strikes |
|
|
458 | (5) |
|
Bargaining in the Public Sector: The Threat of Arbitration |
|
|
463 | (3) |
|
|
466 | (21) |
|
The Theory of Union Wage Effects |
|
|
466 | (4) |
|
Evidence of Union Wage Effects |
|
|
470 | (2) |
|
Evidence of Union Total Compensation Effects |
|
|
472 | (1) |
|
The Effects of Unions on Employment |
|
|
473 | (1) |
|
The Effects of Unions on Productivity and Profits |
|
|
473 | (2) |
|
Normative Analyses of Unions |
|
|
475 | |
|
Example 13.1 The Effects of Deregulation on Trucking and Airlines |
|
|
454 | (7) |
|
Example 13.2 Permanent Replacement of Strikers |
|
|
461 | (14) |
|
Example 13.3 Do Right-to-Work Laws Matter? |
|
|
475 | (3) |
|
Empirical Study What Is the Gap between Union and Nonunion Pay? The Importance of Replication in Producing Credible Estimates |
|
|
478 | (4) |
|
Appendix 13A Arbitration and the Bargaining Contract Zone |
|
|
482 | (5) |
|
|
487 | (30) |
|
|
488 | (3) |
|
Earnings Inequality Since 1980: Some Descriptive Data |
|
|
491 | (7) |
|
The Occupational Distribution |
|
|
492 | (2) |
|
Changes in Relative Wages |
|
|
494 | (1) |
|
Relative Changes in Hours of Work |
|
|
495 | (1) |
|
Growth of Earnings Dispersion within Human Capital Groups |
|
|
496 | (2) |
|
Summarizing the Dimensions of Growing Inequality |
|
|
498 | (1) |
|
The Underlying Causes of Growing Inequality |
|
|
498 | (19) |
|
|
499 | (2) |
|
Changes in Institutional Forces |
|
|
501 | (1) |
|
|
502 | |
|
Example 14.1 Labor's Share of Total Income: ``Raw'' Labor vs. Human Capital |
|
|
498 | (9) |
|
Example 14.2 Changes in the Premium to Education at the Beginning of the Twentieth Century |
|
|
507 | (1) |
|
Empirical Study Do Parents' Earnings Determine the Earnings of Their Children? The Use of Intergenerational Data in Studying Economic Mobility |
|
|
508 | (4) |
|
Appendix 14A Lorenz Curves and Gini Coefficients |
|
|
512 | (5) |
|
|
517 | (36) |
|
A Stock-Flow Model of the Labor Market |
|
|
519 | (4) |
|
|
520 | (1) |
|
Rates of Flow Affect Unemployment Levels |
|
|
521 | (2) |
|
|
523 | (7) |
|
|
524 | (3) |
|
Effects of Unemployment Insurance Benefits |
|
|
527 | (3) |
|
|
530 | (6) |
|
Occupational and Regional Unemployment Rate Differences |
|
|
530 | (2) |
|
International Differences in Long-Term Unemployment |
|
|
532 | (1) |
|
Do Efficiency Wages Cause Structural Unemployment? |
|
|
533 | (3) |
|
Demand-Deficient (Cyclical) Unemployment |
|
|
536 | (6) |
|
|
536 | (4) |
|
Financing U.S. Unemployment Compensation |
|
|
540 | (2) |
|
|
542 | (2) |
|
When Do We Have Full Employment? |
|
|
544 | (9) |
|
Defining the Natural Rate of Unemployment |
|
|
545 | (1) |
|
Unemployment and Demographic Characteristics |
|
|
545 | (1) |
|
Demographic Change and the Natural Rate |
|
|
546 | (1) |
|
What Is the Natural Rate? |
|
|
547 | |
|
Example 15.1 Unemployment Insurance and Seasonal Unemployment: A Historical Perspective |
|
|
543 | (5) |
|
Empirical Study Do Reemployment Bonuses Reduce Unemployment? The Results of Social Experiments |
|
|
548 | (5) |
Answers to Odd-Numbered Review Questions and Problems |
|
553 | (36) |
Name Index |
|
589 | (6) |
Subject Index |
|
595 | |